We spend billions of dollars trying to understand the origins of the universe, while we still don't understand the conditions for a stable society, a functioning economy, or peace.
(D. Helbing quoted from here)
The publication The Network of Global Corporate Control --- watch a TEDx talk about it --- has gained quite some attention in the news (for instance, sciencenews.org and newscientist.com, which went viral) and the blogosphere (for instance, planetsave.com, physorg.com and johncarlosbaez.wordpress.com). Because some reactions have been particularly hostile, for instance Ms. Yves Smith from Naked Capitalism (see also our responses here and in their comment section), or have inspired the conspiracy theory camp, please let me recapitulate what our paper is and isn't and address some of the voiced concerns, in order to avoid misconceptions. (If you are only interested in our responses to critiques - for instance, computing control from ownership and the notion of control in the financial sector - please see Section 8 below.)
Ownership network, more info and 3d video on youtube.
In a nutshell, it's an empirical and interdisciplinary effort to understand a vast economic dataset using methods from the study of complex networks. The analysis focuses, on the one hand on ownership, and on the other hand on control, and reports novel findings for both. It should be noted that ownership is an objective, measurable quantity and that control has to be estimated from it. As in all fields of science, classification and quantification are the first necessary steps in the process of in-depth understanding of novel phenomena.
You are also cordially invited to join the discussion at PLoS ONE, where our paper is "available for commenting and debate by the readers, making [it] the start of a scientific conversation".
1.) The dataset
It is comprised of ownership relations of 37 million economic agents (natural persons, families, foundations, government agencies, listed and unlisted companies, etc.) from early 2007, located in 194 countries. We identify and focus on about 43k transnational corporations (TNCs) in 116 countries, defining a network of 600k nodes.
It is Bureau van Dijk's commercial Orbis database, used, among others, by reinsurance companies, banks and government agencies.
We started in 2007 with our first cross-country study and then did this current global analysis. Yes, it would be very interesting to analyze a more recent network snapshot. However, it is also interesting to see the network shortly before the financial collapse in 2008. Moreover, other national ownership network studies have shown that clusters of powerful agents were very resilient and unaffected by external forces ([3] and [4]). So perhaps the observed power-structure in this 2007 dataset is still surviving the turmoil today...
2.) The research questions
a.) What is the global architecture of ownership (e.g., TNCs may remain isolated, cluster in separated coalitions, or form a large connected component)?
b.) How is control distributed globally?
c.) Who are the key economic actors?
3.) Methods
a.) Our novel methodology extends the known methods for computing control from ownership, and remedies their shortcomings.
b.) Control is proxied by the potential control over the TNCs operating revenue, referred to as network control in the paper. This estimate the percentage of control from the network of direct and indirect ownership relations (using three different models) and multiples this level of control with the operating revenue of the firms a shareholder is connected to (directly and indirectly).
c.) This measure of control can be understood as a quantity flowing through the network, as the methodology is highly attuned to indirect relations between nodes.
d.) Our study is also relevant to the field of complex networks in general, since the methodology can be applied to discover influential nodes in any network where resources are flowing along weighted directed edges.
4.) Novel findings
a.) The network is seen to organize as follows: there are many (~23k) small clusters of connected nodes (called weakly connected components) and then there is one huge connected component, where 77% of all the nodes are located. See the scaling-law distribution of the sizes of the weakly connected components in Figure S6 in the Supporting Information. Interestingly, although 64% of the TNCs are scattered among the many small connected components, they only account for 6% of the operating revenue. In other words, 1/3 of the TNCs are found in the huge connected component and represent nearly all the value. See Figure 2B in the main text.
b.) The topology of this largest weakly connected component has a tiny, but dominant core (in network speak: the largest strongly connected component defining a bow-tie topology) of about 1300 mostly US and GB financial intermediaries. This observation has possible implications for global systemic risk and global market competition (see more in item 7.).
c.) The economics literature would have us think that ownership relations of US and GB financial institutions should not organize as a tightly-knit group owning the majority in each other (i.e., cross-shareholdings and business groups, the paradigm of widely held firms, and the Atlantic or stock market or arm's-length "type" of capitalism, see references in Section 1.2.2 in [1])
d.) The distribution of control (i.e., the potential control over the TNCs value) is unprecedentedly skewed. It takes the shape of a log-normal distribution (see Figure S3 of the Supporting Information) and is roughly an order of magnitude more unequally distributed than wealth (in developed countries). To give some numbers:
i.) 737 top economic agents in the network of 600508 nodes control 80% of the value (operating revenue) of the 43060 TNCs.
ii.) The core, comprised of 1318 nodes, holds 39% of the control.
iii.) There are 147 top agents in the core, controlling 38.4%.
e.) The top actors are in the core and hence are interconnected and do not carry out their business in isolation.
Observe, that findings a.) to c.) are based solely on the objective ownership data, and require no computation of control. Additional information here and here.
5.) Bottom line
a.) Economists are only slowly starting to turn their attention to economic networks. This said, there is an interesting gap in the literature regarding the tools and models used to do so (see Section 1.2.3 in [1]). This is the first analysis of a global dataset on ownership, using a complex networks approach.
b.) It is a starting point for future research. Determining the true implications is up to other scholars to debate on.
c.) Open question: is the core of top actors an emergent property or the result of planned coordination? We tend to think it is an emergent property of the network dynamics.
6.) What the paper isn't
a.) Pushing an economics or socio-political agenda.
b.) Promoting conspiracy theories.
c.) An exact, unambiguous measurement of real-world control.
"Because interpreting and analyzing these kinds of data is difficult, [Davis] says, the analysis serves more as 'an impression of the moon's surface you get with a telescope. It's not a street map.'" Gerald Davis, economist at the University of Michigan in Ann Arbor, quoted from here.
d.) Alleging that the top agents are colluding.
7.) Why study ownership networks?
a.) Previous studies looked at the impact of globalization forces and corporate governance reforms over time on the network topology and found that there was an unexpected resilient structure of powerful agents which was unaffected by these external forces [3,4].
b.) A cross-country analysis revealed that in markets with many widely held corporations (mostly in Anglo-Saxon countries), this local distribution of ownership actually goes hand in hand with a global concentration of ownership (and control), only visible from the bird's-eye view given by the network perspective [5].
c.) Complex ownership patterns, such as cross-shareholdings (e.g., when firms mutually hold shares of each other), are extensively studied motifs in the corporate governance literature and correspond to strongly connected components in networks. Previous studies (on small samples) have shown that cross-shareholdings significantly reduce competition. Accordingly, antitrust institutions all around the world take the existence of complex cross-shareholding structures very seriously. However, they lack the analytical and quantitative tools to deal with large networks.
d.) For some time economic theory has supported the idea that more connected networks are more stable. In contrast, recently, the work of some scholars as well as the view of some authoritative policy makers predict that a higher level of interconnections among financial institutions can lead to higher systemic risk [6].
e.) The network structure matters: the presence of indirect links can significantly amplify the control (or ownership) held by certain economic agents. If one defines the leverage as the ratio between the control we compute, which takes into account the whole network, and the direct control of agents, the resulting probability distribution is scale free (see Figure 4.10 and Section 4.3.3 in [1]). This means that some agents are able to gain a high level of control because of the presence of indirect ownership relations. Usually, this happens by shareholders having control over small firms, which in turn control larger corporations and so forth. Such ownership structures are also called pyramids but were never studied at a global level. Recall the pyramidal group of indirect ownership around Marco Tronchetti Provera, allowing him to control Telecom Italia, one of the world's largest telecom companies, with a disproportional small amount of equity.
f.) General network measures have meaning in ownership networks: the (scaling-law) distribution of the out-degree gives a measure of portfolio diversification (see Figure S5A in the Supporting Information); the distribution of the sizes of the weakly connected components gives a measure of how integrated or fragmented a market is (see the scaling-law distribution in Figure S6 in the Supporting information); the position of an agent in the network can be indicative of its importance.
8.) Problems'n'Answers:
P1: "OMG they discovered financial institutions hold shares! What a scandal!"
A1: It is obvious that large mutual funds own many shares. However, what we are saying is that the potential control they have is surprisingly high. A portfolio manager would arguably go for a diversification strategy and not a controlling one.
P2: "Everybody knows this. It is all so obvious."
A2: There is a big difference between suspecting the existence of a fact and in empirically demonstrating it. We are not aware of an existing study which gives actual empirical evidence of these findings, which some common wisdom indeed anticipated.
"'This is empirical evidence of what’s been understood anecdotally for years,' says information theorist Brandy Aven of the Tepper School of Business at Carnegie Mellon in Pittsburgh." (quote from here).
P3: "You cannot really infer control from ownership."
A3: The separation of ownership and control has been debated in the scholarly literature for decades (see references in Section 6.2.1 in [1]). Although there are many aspects which make the estimation of control from ownership hard to asses (nonvoting shares, dual classes of shares, multiple voting rights, golden shares, voting right ceilings, proxy votes, etc.), researchers have provided, and extensively used, different simple models believed to proxy the control gained from ownership, such as the linear model, assuming the one-share-one-vote principle, or a threshold model, assigning unequivocal control if the percentage of ownership exceeds the threshold. Quite a lot of attention has been devoted to the analysis of ownership and control of individual corporations and of small groups of firms, but never has a large ownership network been investigated. In [5] we added a novel model, that looks at the relative distribution of shares. Even with a small shareholding, if all others hold significantly smaller shares, this model assigns a high level of control.
We computed control using all three fundamentally different models. Neither the topology of the network, nor the distribution of control, nor the identity of the top holders significantly changes in these different scenarios. This unexpected robustness, or invariance, of such global control measures is encouraging, because it means that neither are the models computing arbitrary numbers, nor can the three models have the same bias in computing control the wrong way. So, although for individual agents the computation of direct control can appear arbitrary, the existence of this "aggregated" agreement in the computation is indeed a positive indication that the results are in fact not just spurious or an artifact of the model details. But, as we caution, these numbers are, in any case, an approximation.
P4: "But funds don't exert control."
A4: The question, if funds do or do not exert control, is still being debated in the scholarly literature. It is known that US mutual funds do not always seek to exert control. However, this applies only to them operating in the US. Indeed, the same funds have been shown to exert their power when operating in Europe. We are not aware of a systematic global study about the control financial institutions wield over the companies they have ownership in world-wide. Moreover, control is defined in these studies in a very specific way (for instance the propensity to vote against the management when it comes to issues of corporate governance). In any case, there are 49 mutual funds among the top 737 top holders.
Control can be exerted in ways which are not always visible. We state: "For example, a mutual fund owning some percent of a large corporation may try to impose job cuts because of a weak economic situation. This can happen: (i) without voting and (ii) although the fund does not plan to keep these shares for many years. In this case, the influence of the mutual fund has a direct impact on the company and its employees. Furthermore, mutual funds with shares in many corporations may try to pursue similar strategies across their entire portfolio." Moreover, studies on the network of directors, the boards they serve on, and the interlocks, have revealed these networks to be scale free [7]. This means a few directors are on very many boards. These ties could also be seen as potential channels, through which control can be exerted covertly, when the directors meet in person.
In being cautious, we cannot exclude that the top holders we identify do not globally exert their power in some way. Especially, if we allow for the fact, that control can also be exerted covertly. This is why we talk about potential power in the context of the control numbers we compute. Even if some top holders indeed do assume a passive role, this could be by their own choosing and change anytime.
For references, consult Section 6.2.5 in [1]. and generally Section 6.2 for more concerns that have been addressed.
9.) And finally...
As the world around us is becoming more complex and interconnected, and indeed so at an increasing speed, we believe in the following, in order to try and gain more understanding:
a.) Keep an open mind and question all assumptions, also supposedly established ones.
b.) Let the data speak, not dogmas.
c.) Take the interconnectedness serious: look for and try and understand the network behind complex phenomena.
d.) Use formal tools that can deal with huge amounts of data and complexity in general.
10.) Sources
[1] Ownership Networks and Corporate Control: Mapping Economic Power in a Globalized World, J.B. Glattfelder, 2010
[2] Industrial organization from a geographical and network perspective, S. Vitali, 2010
[3] (Kogut and Walker, 2001)
[4] (Corrado and Zollo, 2006)
[5] (Glattfelder and Battiston, 2009)
[6] (Battiston, Delli Gatti, Gallegati, Greenwald and Stiglitz; 2009)
[7] (Battiston and Catanzaro; 2004)